Radical media, politics and culture.

Ned Rossiter, "Creative Labour and the Role of Intellectual Property"

Ned Rossiter writes: Here's a report on creative labour that I've written for the
fibreculture [fc] list.


"Creative Labour and the Role of Intellectual Property"

Ned Rossiter, September 2003

Here's my report based on the survey I conducted for the fibrepower
panel initiated by Kate Crawford and Esther Milne -- Intellectual
Property—Intellectual Possibilities (Brisbane, July 03). I wanted to
explore in some empirical fashion the relationship between
intellectual property and creative labour. Why?Largely because
such a relationship is the basis for defining what is meant by
creative industries, according to the seminal and much cited mapping
document produced by Blair's Creative Industries Task Force (CITF).


Despite the role IP plays in defining and providing a financial and
regulatory architecture for the creative and other informational or
knowledge industries, there is remarkably little attention given by
researchers and commentators to the implications of IP in further
elaborating conceptual, political and economic models for the
creative industries. There is even greater indifference towards
addressing the impact of exploiting the IP of those whose labour
power has been captured: young people, for the most part, working in
the creative and culture industries. Angela McRobbie's work is one
of the few exceptions.


At a different level, I was curious to see how a mailing list might
contribute in a collaborative fashion to the formation of a research
inquiry in which the object of study -- creative labour and IP -- is
partially determined by the list itself. Finally, after levelling
critiques at various times and occasions against what Terry Flew
(2001) identifies as the 'new media empirics', I thought it necessary
to engage in a more direct way with this nemesis-object: what, after
all, can a new media empirics do and become when it is driven through
what I've developed elsewhere (or rather, syphoned from larger and
older media theory, informatics and philosophy debates) as a
processual model of media and communications? (Rossiter, 2003b) I'll
address this question in the concluding section of this report.


As I noted in an earlier paper (Rossiter, 2003a) posted to fc: The
list of sectors identified as holding creative capacities in the CITF
Mapping Document include: film, music, television and radio,
publishing, software, interactive leisure software, design, designer
fashion, architecture, performing arts, crafts, arts and antique
markets, architecture and advertising. The Mapping Document seeks to
demonstrate how these sectors consist of '... activities which have
their origin in individual creativity, skill and talent and which
have the potential for wealth and job creation through generation and
exploitation of intellectual property' (CITF: 1998/2001). The CITF's
identification of intellectual property as central to the creation of
jobs and wealth firmly places the creative industries within
informational and knowledge economies.


In posting the survey questionnaire to the list, I was interested in
ascertaining the following:


1. the extent to which respondents perceived their primary activities
(i.e., activities other than eating, sleeping, watching TV, having
sex, substance abuse, etc -- though I guess many would argue that
they are indeed primary activities, and perhaps also creative ones!)
to correspond with "creativity", however that term might be
understood (n.b., the survey synopsis clearly framed creativity in
relation to the Creative Industries discourse, so the latitude for
interpreting the term creativity was relatively circumscribed).


2. whether a very partial mapping of the fc network produced results
similar to the sectors identified in the CITF Mapping Document.
Whatever the results, I was interested in what they might then say
about national, regional or State manifestations of the creative
industries: is Australia's CI the same as the UK? Is there a
temporal factor at work? (i.e., given the time of development,
incubation, etc., would a mapping exercise produce different results
depending of when and how it was conducted?)


3. to establish whether respondents perceived or understood an
extant relationship between their labour and intellectual property.


4. to find out whether IP in the workplace makes work a political issue.


At the time of the survey, the fc list had just over 700 subscribers
(June, 03). All responses came on the same day I posted the survey,
most within a few hours of it appearing on list. (This in itself
perhaps says something interesting about the 'attention economy' of
email lists and the time in which any posting may receive a
response: i.e., while the Stones could sing about the redundancy of
newspapers after a day, do list postings have a life of 3 or so
hours? Not so bad actually, though it's probably much less -- more
like seconds, depending on whether a post is read or not.)


Of the 700 or so subscribers then, I received 7 responses. That's 1%
of all list subscribers, a lovely sample to be sure. One of the
respondents provided a follow-up response as well. There was one
other query from someone asking whether they could do the survey even
though they thought they weren't a creative worker; they were a
copyright lawyer -- a category Richard Florida assigns to 'creative
professionals' -- 'business and finance, law, health care and related
fields") as distinct from the core Creative Class: 'people in science
and engineering, architecture and design, education, art, music and
entertainment, whose economic function is to create new ideas, new
technology and/or new creative content' (2002: 8). Curiously, there
is no mention -- at least in this initial definition -- of the role
intellectual property plays in constituting a 'creative class'.1

No
doubt there are national-cultural and socio-political explanations
for the differences between how creative workers are perceived and
constituted in the UK and North America. To my knowledge, there is
yet to be a study that inquires into the different national and
regional formations of creative
industries/classes/economies/cultures. One could argue that OECD
research papers and reports along with those by neo-conservative,
libertarian think-tanks such as Demos and the Cato Institute do such
work; however, while they certainly compile statistics and bring a
dual mode of commentary and hyperbole to such figures, they do very
little by way of historical, political economy and cultural analysis
of the variable conditions that have led to the emergence of creative
labour and its attendant industries across these geopolitical regions.


REFLEXIVITY and EMPIRICAL RESEARCH


While the sample I'm drawing on is most certainly small, it is not
insignificant. Indeed, I think its minutiae corresponds to larger
patterns of creative labour in Australia, and most probably
elsewhere, as I extrapolate below. Interestingly, I'm told by a
psychologist friend researching the formation of depression in
migrants that current, more reflexive literature on quantitative,
empirical research argues that the fuss over sample sizes (i.e., the
need to have a large sample if the claims/results are to have any
scholastic purchase on the phantasm of veridicality) is problematic
in all sorts of ways (see Edwards, 1997; Silverman, 2001). For
instance, at what point can one say a sample is representative of the
community, user-consumers, demographic, socio-technical network, etc.
under analysis? As Pierre Bourdieu (1973) argued so acutely and with
such verve, public opinion does not exist. What exists, for
Bourdieu, is the discursive form of the survey or opinion poll, the
interests that drive it, and the ends to which it is put. Of course
my own survey is not immune from the sort of critical, theoretical
and political interests I bring to the analysis of responses.


Then there's the whole pseudo-scientific language of "observation",
as though there might have ever been some sort of impartiality
underpinning the process of enacting the survey. Scott Lash
associates such a paradigm with "reflective modernisation" and the
work of Giddens, Habermas and Parsonian structural functionalism and
linear systems theory: 'The idea of reflective belongs to the
philosophy of consciousness of the first modernity.... To reflect is
to somehow subsume the object under the subject of knowledge.
Reflection presumes apodictic knowledge and certainty. It presumes a
dualism, a scientific attitude in which the subject is in one realm,
the object of knowledge in another' (2003: 51). In contrast to a
reflective first modernity, Lash posits a reflexive second modernity
and non-linear systems of communication and risk comprising of
quasi-objects and subjects and their theorisation by the likes of
Luhmann, Beck and Latour, along with Castells' network logic of flows:


'Second modernity reflexivity is about the emergent *demise* of the
distinction between structure and agency altogether....
Second-modernity reflexivity presumes a move towards immanence that
breaks with the [ontological] dualisms of structure and agency....
The reflexivity of the second modernity presumes the existence of
non-linear systems. Here system dis-equilibrium and change are
produced internally to the system through feedback loops. These are
open systems. Reflexivity now is at the same time system
*de*-stabilization' (2003: 49-50).


The extent to which reflexive non-linear systems wholly dispense with
or depart from a constitutive outside in favour of a logic of
immanence is a problematic I have begun to question with other fc
members in an earlier posting to the list (Rossiter, 2003a).2 Like
the question of and tension between new media empirics and processual
media theory, it is a problematic I'll return to in my concluding
remarks.


I think one reason I received even 7 responses had much to do with
prior knowledges and trust established between myself as "observer"
and the "participants" in this survey: ie, I had either met or knew
very well 6 of the 7 respondents. Here, it is worth turning again to
Bourdieu (1992), who frames the concept of reflexivity in
particularly succinct terms: 'What distresses me when I read some
works by sociologists is that people whose profession is to
objectivize the social world prove so rarely able to objectivize
themselves, and fail so often to realize that what their apparently
scientific discourse talks about is not the object but their relation
to the object' (68-69). Put in terms of non-linear systems theory,
the on- and off-line relationships, trust and symbolic economy I had
established largely through an online network operated as a feedback
loop into the call for interest in and responses to this current
survey. Obvious as it may sound, this very historical and social
dimension to a communicative present actively destabilises any
rhetorical claims that I might attempt in the name of conducting a
survey that follows the scientific principles of objectivity and
impartiality and methodologies befitting quantitative research. The
only thing that is remotely impartial about this survey is the
anonymity of the respondents as I present them here.


Feedback loops further destabilise the very object-ness of this
report as a discrete posting to a mailing list insofar as anyone who
responds to this report breaks up components of the report by way of
selective quoting or paraphrasing and interjecting their own
critiques or comments. Many of us do this when we reply to an email,
separating the sender's text from our own; in so doing, we are
translating or mimicking the effect of dialogue. Such a process is
registered in a material, symbolic form in the dissipative,
non-linear structure of discussion threads as they appear in the
mailing list's archives. Further registration of feedback loops are
made in the googlisation of this combinatory knowledge and
information formation, where any particular posting has the potential
to move up the vertical scale of "hits" depending on the key words
used in the user's search, the online links made to the posting, and
the popularity of the posting: in short, the coding of the google
software program plays a determining role in the hierarchisation of
information that is then further shaped by the interests and habits
of users. The economy and architecture of the google search engine
has been subject to considerable debate and discussion in lists such
as fc and nettime, along with many other online fora, print and
electronic media. If this posting, for example, were made on any
number of web conferencing systems, collaborative text filtering
sites or blogs, such as slashdot.org, indymedia.org, makeworld.org or
discordia (http://discordia.us), then a very different information
architecture of feedback loops would prevail. Ok, time now to get to
some substance of the survey.


CREATIVITY -- What's In a Name?


When I asked respondents what creative activities they engaged in, a
list of 4-6 fields, practices or sectors of creativity by any one
person was compiled. These included writing, performing and
producing music; writing academic and policy papers (considered by
one respondent and assumed by others as 'creative endeavours');
photography; design (interactive, information, education); publishing
and editing; new media arts (dv, net.art, print, electronic music);
painting; and creative writing. Three things stand out for me here:


1) Irrespective of whether or not respondents went on to identify
themselves as part of the Creative Industries project, however that
might be understood, the range of creative activities any single
person might undertake suggests that diversity rather than
specialisation is a defining feature of creative workers. This isn't
to say that specialisation doesn't occur in any particular idiom of
creativity -- I think it's safe to assume that it would, but rather
that respondents were not limited to one particular set creative
skills, trainings, or passions. Thus these respondents are clear
exemplars of the so-called fragmented postmodern subject, traversing
a range of institutional locations and cultural dispositions.


2) Many of the respondents are engaged in academic work either on a
full-time, continuing basis or as sessional, casual teachers. In
both cases, university related activities and non-university related
activities were assumed to hold creative dimensions. If nothing else,
the diversity of creative activities identified by respondents
indicates the complexity of labour in the contemporary university,
further suggesting that: a) the university cannot accommodate the
diverse interests and economic necessities of its constituent labour
power, and/or b) that individuals wish to distinguish between the
kind of work they do at university and its concomitant values and the
kind of work they do outside the university, or c) that there is zone
of indistinction, if you will, between the university and its
so-called outside, given that all sectors of cultural production and
intellectual labour are today subject to market economies. The
extent to which tensions exist between these realms, or whether they
are better characterised as a sort of zone of indistinction that
cannot be reduced in such a manner, varies, I suspect, according to
the contingencies of time, interests, values, labour conditions, age,
class, gender, etc. of individuals as they are located in different
institutional settings. Each of the above possibilities corresponds
with the economic and labour conditions peculiar to the creative
industries operating in the UK, as McRobbie explains:


'Those working in the creative sector cannot simply rely on old
working patterns associated with art worlds, they have to find new
ways of "working" the new cultural economy, which increasingly means
holding down three or even four "projects" at once. In addition,
since these projects are usually short term, there have to be other
jobs to cover the short-fall when the project ends. The individual
becomes his or her own enterprise, sometimes presiding over two
separate companies at the same time' (2002: 519; see also Beck, 1992:
127-150; Bauman, 2001: 17-30).


3) There is much overlap between this list of creative activities and
the CITF's list of creative sectors, with the exception that
traditional arts and crafts and antiques do not figure in the former;
this comes as no surprise, given that the survey was conducted on a
listserve for critical Internet research and culture. As for how
this list relates to Richard Florida's composition of the Creative
Class in the US, there is an obvious absence in my survey of
engineers and scientists. Again, you might say this should come as
no surprise; one could, however, describe software programmers,
"codeworkers", game designers, etc. as computer scientists or
information engineers - though no doubt there'd be some disciplinary
and perhaps ontological dispute over this.


Having established that they all are engaged in creative activities
of one kind or another, there were then considerable differences
amongst respondents as to whether they perceived themselves as
engaged in the Creative Industries. Two respondents said they didn't
- one being a bit hesitant as to whether they did or not, the other
indifferent, implying the term was no more than a 'tag' associated
with 'official places' and 'certain faculties'. Four respondents
stated that they did associate their activities with the Creative
Industries, some more emphatically so than others. One of those
responded by writing that 'Yeah, but I'm a special case :)',
indicating that creativity, at least for this person, comes with a
sense of individuality, difference and exception. Yet such
subjectivities carry more baggage than this. As Angela McRobbie
notes, 'Individualization is not about individuals *per se*, as about
new, more fluid, less permanent social relations seemingly marked by
choice or options. However, this convergence has to be understood as
one of contestation and antagonism' (2002: 518). Much of this report
seeks to unravel various tensions that underpin labour practices
within the creative industries.


A seventh respondent took a more reflexive, marxian and historically
informed position, choosing to problematise and open up the question
in the following way: 'All industry is creative; all human activity
creates something; and nearly all human activity is subsumed under
industrial imperatives (including the consumption of media and other
products). Therefore I think this is probably a question whose
answer is presupposed in the historical facts of its own terms'. On
these grounds, then, irrespective of whether respondents did or
didn't identify their creative activities with Creative Industries,
there is a sense amongst these respondents -- perhaps unconscious --
that there is an "idea" of what constitutes the creative industries,
and respondent's identification with those industries is based,
perhaps, on whether one meets the criteria or fits into the
discursive boundaries, categories, or ethos of the Creative
Industries, as established in part in the survey's preamble.


INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY and CREATIVITY


The importance of intellectual property (copyrights, patents,
trademarks) as a source of income was met with a mixed response. For
one person it was important, for the rest it wasn't, at least in an
exclusive sense: labour was paid for on an hourly basis or IP was
assigned to the company or publisher commissioning the work; in other
instances remuneration from IP contributed to a respondent's income,
but wasn't relied upon as a primary source of income. Creative
workers were thus primarily alienated from their intellectual
property in one form or another. Such a response clearly signals a
tension and power relationship with regard to the CITF definition of
creative industries as those activities that have 'the potential for
wealth and job creation through generation and exploitation of
intellectual property'. Thus despite all the rhetoric around
informational and creative labour consisting of "horizontal" and
"fluid" modes of production, distribution and exchange, clearly there
remains vertical, hierarchical dimensions within the "New Economy".
If IP is to function as the mainstay of capital accumulation within
informational economies, it doesn't take much imagination to foresee
industrial, legal and political dispute focussing on the
juridico-political architecture of IP. The extent to which workers
are able to mobilise their potential power in an effective manner
(i.e., in a way that protects and secures their interests whilst
inventing new information architectures) depends, I would suggest, on
their capacity to organise themselves as a sociopolitical force.
I'll address this issue in relation to the problem of immaterial
labour in more detail below.


Respondents found IP a source of tension not only at the level of
financial remuneration; a tension prevailed around the concept of IP
as well. In response to the question of whether intellectual
property is important as a principle -- that is, as a system or
framework consisting of rules and beliefs that enables the
transformation of labour into legal, moral and potentially economic
values -- one person stated that they found it of no importance at
all. All others found it was, though the response, as expected, was
mixed: 'Yes, but in a negative sense. The whole structure of IP has
turned into a perversion of its intended principles: namely, that
alienation rather than one's inalienable rights in one's own work is
the guiding principle of IP law. Put differently, rights are seen to
exist only so that they can be sold. That is a function of capital,
long since dead. I would prefer a rights structure that existed to
ensure the free flow of ideas'. In a similar vein, though without
the libertarian overtone, another respondent writes: 'It is important
to me as a principle to be critiqued, developed and (in some cases)
rejected. The arm of IP is extending in several directions and in
many industries -- and it's that reach that needs to be reviewed with
some urgency'.


A third respondent strongly rejected the idea that IP might be
understood in terms of principles: 'No', they write, 'It's important
to me as a discursive field!' By my reading, such a statement
suggests that the respondent understands principles as holding some
kind of unchanging, transcendental and universal status, while a
discursive field is historically and culturally mutable and holds the
potential for local intervention by actors endowed with such
capacities. (A similar distinction is often made in philosophy
between the universality of morals and the contingencies of ethics.)
The idea of IP as a discursive field rather than a principle is also
interesting in relation to the second response tabled above, which
implies that limits need to be established with regard to IP and the
extent to which it governs areas of life previously outside a market
economy. Current debates around patenting the human genome, database
access to DNA information on sperm and embryo composition and their
relationship to insurance premiums and future employment
possibilities (see Gattica for the filmic version of this scenario),
the pressure on developing countries to import GM food coupled with
uneven, neo-colonial trade agreements along with conditions imposed
by the World Bank and IMF's structural adjustment programs, and so
forth are the most obvious examples that come to mind here.


INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY and the LABOUR CONTRACT


The tension associated with IP was further extended to the workplace,
with all but one of the respondents noting that they had heard of and
in some instances personally experienced conflicts over IP issues.
If such accounts are the norm rather than the exception, this clearly
signals a need for much greater attention to be given to the role of
IP in the workplace, and the status it holds as a legal and social
architecture governing the conditions of creative production, job
satisfaction, employer-employee relations and thus life in general.
While only two respondents reported of losing a job or contract for
refusing to assign IP to their employer, many commented on the
problems of such a condition -- as one person noted: 'This is common
in film music now: if you don't sell your rights to the film maker,
you are not given the contract'. Another highlighted the legal and
institutional distinction between private and state sectors.
Addressing the Australian situation, this respondent notes that
government bodies such as councils and departments 'are exempt from
recognising author rights under the current copyright act - therefore
to refuse to hand over intellectual rights in these cases is to
refuse to work'.


Here is a curious and paradoxical case in point in which the call to
a 'refusal of work' -- derived from 1960s radical workers' movements
of the 1960s by Italian autonomists such as Paolo Virno -- is
jerry-wired into the system itself, albeit with a significant proviso
of political proportion. The autonomists seek to liberate work from
relations of waged labour and the capitalist State; to unleash 'a
mass defection or exodus' and in so doing subtract the labour power
which sustains the capitalist system, affirming the 'creative
potential of our practical capacities' in the process (see Hardt,
1996: 6). There's a bit of a different rub, however, in a capitalist
logic of post-Fordist flexible accumulation, whose modes of social
and political regulation set the scene for our current informational
paradigm. While the worker within Fordist systems of assembly-line
mass production and mass consumption conditions the possibility of,
to refer to the classic example, the assemblage of motor vehicles
that, ideally, are then sold to the consumer who built the vehicle in
their 8 hour working day, the case of IP and creative labour operates
in substantially different ways.


Within an informational paradigm, the appropriation of labour power
by capitalists does not result in a product so much as a potential.
This potential takes the "immaterial" form of intellectual property
whose value is largely unquantifiable and is subject to the vagaries
of speculative finance markets, "New Economy" style. Thus, in the
case of government institutions that don't recognise an individual's
IP rights, there is nothing to 'hand over' in the first instance.
That is, the right to a refusal of work is not possible; or put
differently, the creative potential or work, as registered in and
transformed into the juridico-political form of IP, is undermined by
the fact that such a social relation -- the hegemonic form of
legitimacy -- is not recognised. As noted by another respondent: 'I
don't think you "lose" a contract for refusing to sign IP over ...
it's more like you never had it in the first place if you do work for
hire'. Instead, one does not so much refuse to work as decline to
provide a service, whose economic value as wage labour -- that is,
labour separated from its product (Marx in Harvey, 1990:104) -- bears
no relationship to the potential economic value generated by the
exploitation of IP. In effect, then, "creativity" goes right under
the radar. Prostitution functions in a similar manner. One does not
buy "love" from the prostitute, one acquires a "service" in the form
of an orgasm, or "little death", with no value in and of itself. The
prostitute's love does not figure in the relationship; love is off
the radar. Like intellectual property, the expression of the orgasm
in a given form -- sperm, for the male who appropriates the labour
power of the prostitute -- nevertheless holds the potential to
translate into economic, social, political and biological values if
its eruption is arranged under different conditions -- the normative
ones peculiar to heterosexual couplings living in advanced economies,
for example.


A couple of respondents, both now working in the higher education
sector, had mixed responses to the kind of conditions such a setting
enabled vis-à-vis labour and IP.


Respondent 1: 'I would always give
in [and sign over IP] when I was self-employed, now I only take jobs
where I'm happy with the IP arrangements'. Such a position is
possible when, as noted earlier, IP is not the primary source of
income. Interestingly, the other respondent anticipates conflicts
over the assignation of IP within university settings --

Respondent 2:
'as i continue to collaborate in university settings, the problem
will arise'. The problem of job security arises where IP policies
can vary substantially from university to university and at an
intra-university level depending on the kind of contract an
individual is able to negotiate with management as universities
undergo increasingly deregulation toward a system that destroys the
legal concept fought for by unions of collective wage agreements. At
my own university, to take a typical example of someone working in
the higher education sector, the subject materials I produce are the
intellectual property of the university. These educational materials
will often incorporate parts of articles I have written or am in the
process of writing. (They will also include lists of references to
articles and debates located in open-access online repositories, as
found in the fibreculture and nettime archives, for example.) And
here, a curious institutional tension over IP emerges: depending on
the publisher, the IP of articles and books I write belongs to the
publisher. One of the respondents noted how this problem of
proprietary rights of academic IP has been dealt with in recent
legislation in Australia: 'the new IP rules (e.g., the one which came
into effect on 14th March) gives the university ownership of all IP
created by staff (with a 'scholarly work' exception). This creates
major problems - for example, academics moving to different
universities who intend to use educational materials they have
developed previously'. Thus the extent to which IP functions as an
architecture of control is and has always been dubious at the level
of the everyday. Just think of what happened with the appearance of
the xerox machine in university settings -- in effect it became a free
license to appropriate the property of writers, with myriad staff and
students reproducing the pages of otherwise copyright protected
materials.


Even if the legal aspects of IP are frequently difficult if not
impossible to regulate, there are important symbolic dimensions to IP
that have implications and impacts at the level of subjectivities and
their degree of legitimacy within institutional and national
settings. Here I am thinking -- yet again -- of that rather chilling
line in the CITF's definition of the Creative Industries in which IP
is not only generated, but more significantly, it is *exploited*.
The exploitation of IP is not simply a matter of extracting the
potential economic value from some inanimate thing; the exploitation
of IP, let us never forget, is always already an exploitation of
people, of the producers of that which is transformed from practice
into property, which in its abstraction is then alienated from those
who have produced it. While there are clear problems with such a
system, IPRs are not necessarily a bad thing. As I've argued
elsewhere, to simply oppose IPRs is not a political option (Rossiter,
2002). Individuals and communities must look for ways in which IPRs
can be exploited for strategic ends. Such a political manoeuvre is
possible, for instance, in efforts to advance Indigenous sovereignty.
To return to the relationship between the exploitation of IP and the
political status of subjectivity, it should be noted that QUT holds a
policy in which students retain control of all IP they produce, with
some exceptions.3 Such a policy initiative seems to be the exception
within an environment of "enterprise universities" (Marginson and
Considine, 2000) whose economic viability depends upon obtaining the
maximum leverage possible within a political economy of partial
deregulation.


INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY and (DIS)ORGANISED LABOUR


Most of the respondents corrected the assumption in my question on
the relationship between collaborative production and the difficulty
of assigning IP rights to individuals or joint-authorship.
Respondents noted that corporations own the creative efforts of both
individuals and collaborations, since the corporation has paid for
that work. This brings me to the final component of the survey -- the
relationship between IP and the problem of disorganised labour. It
seems to me that unions are among the best placed actors to contest
the seemingly foregone conclusion that corporations have an a priori
hold on the appropriation of labour power. As Castells has noted in a
recent interview:


'... with the acceleration of the work process [enabled by new ICTs],
worker's defense continues to be a fundamental issue: they cannot
count on their employers. The problem is that the individualization
of management/worker relationships makes the use of traditional forms
of defense, in terms of collective bargaining and trade union-led
struggles, very difficult except in the public sector. Unions are
realizing this and finding new forms of pressure, sometimes in the
form of consumer boycotts to press for social justice and human
rights. Also, individual explosions of violence by defenseless
workers could be considered forms of resistance' (Castells and Ince,
2003: 29).


However, there is an impasse of paradigmatic proportion to the
potential for unions to assist workers -- particularly younger workers
-- within creative industries or knowledge and information economies.
The so-called strategy of consumer sovereignty is a relatively weak
one, and only further entrenches the problem of individualisation
inasmuch as the potential for a coalition amongst workers is only
further sidelined in favour of that mantra urged on by our
politicians who are so keen to protect "the national interest" --
yes, the national economy is fragile, so enjoy yourself and go out
and shop! There is a general perception that unions and their
capacity to organise labour in politically effective and socially
appealing ways are a thing of the past. To address this issue I will
first table comments from respondents. I will then move on to the
thesis of "immaterial labour", as presented by Lazzarato, Hardt and
Negri, and argue why the condition of "disorganised labour" more
accurately describes the circumstances in which labour finds itself
within an informational paradigm.


Three of the respondents stated they did not belong to a union, one
with perhaps a degree of ironic self-affirmation characteristic of
what Lash and Urry (1994) term 'reflexive individualization': 'Nope',
writes one person, 'I'm a manager and self-employed :7'. In his book
on globalisation, Ulrich Beck identifies a nexus between those who
work for themselves -- a mode of coordination he attributes to
"life-aesthetes" in particular -- and their desire for
'self-development'. He goes on to suggest that such dispositions
lend themselves to 'self-exploitation': 'People are prepared to do a
great deal for very little money, precisely because economic
advantage is individualistically refracted and even assigned an
opposite value. If an activity has greater value in terms of
identity and self-fulfilment, this makes up for and even exalts a
lower level of income' (2000: 150).


Richard Caves prefers to explain the condition of non-union labour in
more economic terms. Citing the example of independent filmmaking,
Caves notes that '30 to 35 per cent of production costs [can be
saved] by operating a nonunion project' (2000:133). In productions
involving union labour, most of these additional costs are a result,
so Caves claims, of inefficient and interventionist management
practices and regulations, which sees workers being paid for standing
around doing nothing. Caves casts unions as manipulative entities
who have a propensity to 'hold-up' production unless their wage
demands are met (132). Issues of creative governance are always
going to have local, national peculiarities, and will vary from
industry to industry. In every case, however, the challenge for
creative workers is, it seems to me, to create work that holds not
only the maximum potential for self-fulfilment and group cooperation
on a project, but just as importantly, creative workers need to
situate themselves in ways that close down the possibility of
exploitation.


The other respondents belonged to various unions or professional
organisations: NTEU (2), MEAA/AJA (2), the College Arts Association
(USA) and APRA, 'which is not really a union, but it primarily
concerned with IP'. All these respondents were aware of their union's
policy on IP issues, though one respondent held a high level of
cynicism: 'I've never heard a union take a credible position on IP'.
The follow up question on the efficacy of unions in instances of
dispute with management over IP elicited further cynicism from
another respondent: 'Unions are too stupid to do this properly. They
are as much a part of the problem since they agree to perverse work
relations. Unions are corporations'. Others noted that disputes of
this nature were 'an ongoing battle on many fronts' and that 'the
MEAA/AJA newsletter often has such stories. Most of it is so
thoroughly covered in case law that the major players don't bother to
buck the system. The case of US freelance Journos seeking payment
for new media republication of their stories seminal'. To summarise:
while the majority of respondents did belong to one or more unions, a
good proportion of these respondents did not seem satisfied with or
have any great faith in the efforts of unions to negotiate disputes
over IP in the workplace.


[end part 1/2: report continues below]